I have yet to read "The Econocracy: The Perils of
Leaving Economics to the Experts" by Joe Earle, Cahal Moran and Zach
Ward-Perkins but I have been reading this review of
the book by Aditya Chakrabortty and it has caused me to reflect further on my
own experience of studying economics.
Like Earle, Moran and Ward-Perkins, I studied for an
undergraduate economics degree at the University of Manchester. To me, in 1965,
the course structure seemed fragmented: I had assumed that I would study mostly
economics (although I had no idea what that involved and had chosen it for
rebellious reasons). I was puzzled by the requirement to study social
anthropology (what did witchcraft among the Azande have to do with anything?)
and politics, although I enjoyed both and found them much easier than my choice
of option, accounting.
The course had in fact provided a very broad base of social
science study, although the links between the different parts of the programme
were not emphasised and it was not until I started my doctoral studies many
years later that the links dawned on me. It was also many years before I
realised that I had been taught by very distinguished scholars in politics (W.J.M.Mackenzie) and
social anthropology (Max
Gluckman).
But what about the economics courses? I remember that the
main textbook was the first edition of An Introduction to Positive Economics by
Richard Lipsey. I remember breathing in the smell of my brand new copy. I also
remember reading the first chapter time after time in the hope that eventually
I would understand it... We also used Samuelson's Economics (a book which gets
its own Wikipedia entry) which I
found much easier to understand. Or perhaps the diagrams were prettier. I
remember that our classes were taught by two young men called David, Colman and
Metcalf, who both went on to have very distinguished academic careers, although
I didn't understand what they talked about.
My main problem with economics was the models. They required
so many assumptions that I couldn't see how the abstractions helped with
understanding the complexity of real life problems. I could - eventually -
grasp the idea behind the trade-off between guns and butter but how exactly did
this explain how decisions about national resources were actually made? What
did the Phillips curve actually mean? This puzzlement extended into aspects of
accounting: I shed tears over double entry bookkeeping for the whole of the
first term until the penny dropped and I managed to produce a balance sheet
that balanced.. but what exactly was the point? I hit this problem again when I
began my PhD work and found that the corporate governance literature was
largely predicated on principal-agent theory, the assumptions of which, to me,
led to a very narrow analysis of my area of interest, board behaviour.*
According to the book review, the Manchester students had a
similar problem with abstract models and prompted by this review I look forward
to reading their account. But Chakrabortty, as he makes clear, was closely
involved with the students and the developments subsequent to their challenge
to the Manchester curriculum and I'd like to hear other views - I'd
particularly like to know how the Manchester lecturers dealt with the
challenge. Chakrabortty also states: "The authors analysed 174
economics modules for seven Russell Group universities, making this the most
comprehensive curriculum review I know of." One could, of course, argue
that Russell Group graduates are more likely to have significant future
influence as economists than graduates from other universities but my former
colleagues were certainly teaching heterodox economics long before the
financial crisis which precipitated the story behind this book.
I like the idea of students challenging the curriculum, not
because it's too challenging for them (not unusual among my accounting students
over the years) but because it doesn't address real world problems. More power
to their elbows!
*the late Sumantra Ghoshal, Professor of Strategic and
International Management at the London business School, argued persuasively that
the teaching of agency theory in business schools had very negative consequences
on actual behaviour. The theory has been broadened more recently with
scholars developing behavioural agency theory models.
Ghoshal, S (2005) Bad Management Theories Are
Destroying Good Management Practices Academy of Management Learning
& Education, Vol. 4, No. 1, 75–91.
No comments:
Post a Comment